16 May, 2012

Explain the emergence of International Political Economy as a field, and why, if at all, it is relevant today?


Explain the emergence of International Political Economy as a field, and why, if at all, it is relevant today?

International Relations (IR) has traditionally focused on questions of war and peace and conflict and co-operation between states. International Political Economy (IPE) is a conscious shift towards understanding issues of wealth and poverty; of who gets what in the international system. The emergence of the discipline will be examined to establish why the period necessitated a new approach within IR. By examining key perspectives of IPE theory, its usefulness and relevance to explaining issues of poverty and wealth and deepening understanding of international relations will then be ascertained.

The very definition of IPE is a contentious issue in itself. Depending on the theoretical perspective subscribed to, different elements of IPE become important. This is why it is important to examine different theoretical perspectives of the field. Whilst some writers perceive IPE as a branch of international relations, others believe that IR should be considered part of political economy. Each theoretical approach defines what constitutes ‘political’ and the ‘economic’ and thus this affects how they fit into the model of ‘political economy’.

The academic discipline of IR arose at the beginning of the twentieth century with the goal of understanding questions of war and peace and making the world a more peaceful place. This focus was maintained as a central aspect of the discipline until the 1960’s as it was relevant to the period; the Second World War and Cold War seemingly highlighted the importance of the focus for the study. “International relations asked the question why nation-states continued to go to war when it was already clear that the economic gains made in war would never exceed the economic costs of doing so… International political economy today…asks why do states fail to act to regulate and stabilize an international financial system which is known to be vitally necessary to the ‘real economy’ but which all the experts in and out of government now agree is in dangerous need of more regulation for its own safety?”[1] With America now established as the hegemon, the balance of power has re-established trade rather than warring relations between states. IPE is a response to a fundamental shift in current affairs which have shifted to issues of poverty and wealth.

Gill & Law suggest there are two reasons for the upsurge in interest in the field of IPE during the 1970’s. The first of these, in 1971, was the changes to the system in the world economy, essentially due to the collapse of the Bretton Woods System and the oil crisis. The system that politicians had established to ensure global economic growth and trade after World War II had been seriously compromised. “Politically weak and economically poor recently decolonized countries were unhappy with their subordinate position in the international economic system.”[2] Consequently, proposals from the UN during the 1970’s called for a ‘New International Economic Order’ to address the imbalance and disparity of wealth between developed and developing countries and improve the economic position of third world countries. This emphasised the interconnectedness of politics and economics. Political measures were taken that changed the rules of the game for the economic marketplace. Secondly, it is suggested that “changes in the academic community which occurred partly as a response to the ‘real’ changes in economic conditions”[3] Growing economic interdependence was significantly affecting US policy. Traditionally ‘low’ politics issues of economics, trade, money and foreign investment which had been previously dismissed as relatively unimportant compared to ‘high’, statesman politics of diplomacy and security began to move up the political agenda. The complex relationship between politics and economics was once again brought to the fore; IPE is the subject which attempts to grasp the relationship between these two key elements.

The important relationship between politics and economics, states and markets has been IR neglected by traditional IR. IPE provides theoretical approaches to understanding the relationship between these issues of wealth and poverty. Scholars generally regard mercantilism, economic liberalism and Marxism as the main theories of IPE. Mercantilism maintains a largely realist perspective focussing on the nation and interaction between states. Economic liberalism can be considered an addition to liberal theory focussing on the individual in the market place. Marxism maintains its own original theoretical perspective focussing on production and class conflict. These can be considered the main theories of the discipline insofar as they provide the core assumptions and values from which IPE as a discipline can be approached.

Mercantilism is connected to the establishment of the modern, sovereign states arising during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Mercantilism is also referred to as statism, protectionism, and economic nationalism. Mercantilists believe that economics should be subordinate to the establishment of a strong state, with political elites at the forefront of the establishment of building the modern state. “Economics is a tool for politics, a basis for political power.”[4] For mercantilists, the international economy is an arena of conflict between opposing national interests, rather than an area of cooperation and mutual gain. The economic competition between states is thus regarded as a ‘zero sum game’; one state’s gain is another’s loss. Additionally, states are wary of other state’s relative economic gain as the material wealth accumulated could be used for establishing military-political power to be used against other states. This clearly reflects much of the neorealist ideology of competition between states. “Its central idea is that economic activities are and should be subordinate to the goal of state building and the interests of the state”[5]

Gilpin suggests that the economic rivalry between states can take two forms; ‘benign’ or ‘malevolent’ mercantilism. Benign mercantilist states take a generally defensive position, attempting to look after their national economic interests in order to ensure their national security without having any overtly negative effects on other states. “Some nationalists consider the safeguarding of national economic interests as the minimum essential to the security and survival of the state.”[6]

Conversely, ‘malevolent’ mercantilist states attempt to exploit the international economy through expansionary policies for example, colonisation. “There are those nationalists who regard the international economy as an arena for imperialist expansion and national aggrandizement.”[7] For mercantilists, economic strength and military political power are two important complementary goals for a state.

“Whereas liberal writers generally view the pursuit of power and wealth, that is, the choice between “guns and butter,” as involving a trade-off, nationalists tend to regard the two goals as being complementary.[8] Mercantilists suggest that because economic resources are essential to maintain and assert national power, conflict is both political and economic. Mercantilists would assert that the pursuit of wealth and power are inextricable goals of states which inevitably overlap. Mercantilists pursue power, self-sufficiency and economic independence rather than interdependence.

In contrast to the mercantilist perspective, economic liberals dismiss theories and policies which subordinate economics to politics. Conversely, economic liberals would suggest that markets are spontaneous; arising to meet demand and the satisfaction of human needs -provided they are free from state interference. “Liberal political theory is committed to free markets and minimal state intervention…individual equality and liberty.”[9]  Liberal ideology maintains the existence of individual rational actors – people acting in the way most beneficial and profitable for themselves, pursuing their own individual interests. Other liberal ideas include the belief in progress and mutual gain from free trade. Liberalism is committed to a free market and demand regulated by the market. “Smith suggests the key notion that the economic marketplace is the main source of progress, cooperation, and prosperity.” [10] Political interference and state regulation is believed to be inimical to this progress, creating conflict and reducing the efficiency of the system.

Economic liberals reject mercantilist notions of the centrality of the state as a central actor in economic affairs; rather, they suggest it is the individual and consumer who is in fact the central actor. In the marketplace they suggest economic exchange is a positive sum game, individuals and companies reap greater rewards than they input into production due to increased efficiency. Liberals suggest this starting point is useful for understanding market economics and also economics. Consequently, economic liberals reject the mercantilist notion that one state’s economic gain necessarily must be at the expense of another. The global economy is perceived as a as a sphere of cooperation amongst states and individuals and the mutual benefit of all and thus, the international economy should be based on this free trade model. Although classic liberal theorists would argue against any form of state interference, promoting instead a laissez faire economic system, neo-liberals accept some state interference in the form of policy measures to manage the workings of the economy can maximise the efficiency of the state. Keynesian ideas of a market ‘wisely managed’[11] by the state lent a positive perspective of the state as an actor who could give direction and provide political management of the market. The liberal view seems now to be shifting back towards an entirely laissez faire liberalist model with the belief that unfettered economic globalization will be prosperous for the whole world.

The Marxist approach to IPE is a fundamental critique of economic liberalism, rejecting the notion that the economy is beneficial to all as a positive-sum game. Rather, Marxists perceive the economy as a site of class inequality and exploitation. Marxists apply the mercantilist zero-sum game between states and apply it to class; one class can benefit but only at the expense of another. “Marxists agree with mercantilists that politics and economics are closely intertwined; both reject the liberal view of an economic sphere operating under its own laws. But where mercantilists see economics as a tool of politics, Marxists put economics first and politics second.”[12]

Marxists believe there to be two antagonistic social classes within the economy; the bourgeoisie who own the means of production and the proletariat who sell their labour to the bourgeoisie. By exploiting the labour, the bourgeoisie generate capitalist profit. This is because the labour puts in more work than it gets back in pay. Marx perceived capitalism as a precursor to a social revolution where the means of production would be placed under common ownership. Marxists suggest that economic production is the basis for all other human activities, including politics. For Marxists, states are controlled by the ruling class and driven by the interests of the bourgeoisie. This means war and conflict between states is the physical manifestation of capitalist class competition between states and as capitalism expands around the world, the competition between the capitalist classes follows. As such, Marxists perceive the history of IPE as the history of capitalism expanding across the globe.

Mercantilism, neo-Liberalism and Marxism all expose different aspects of the complex relationship between politics and economics. However, these theories in themselves have taken their arguments too far from the logical conclusion. Mercantilists’ claim that politics is in full control of economics is clearly incorrect. Although politics provides the framework for economics to function, the market has an important effect on the political agenda. However, the extent of this is not as far as Marxists would assert; although it is influential, economics does not determine politics. Similarly, although economic liberals would suggest the market is autonomous, this is not entirely true. Yes, the market does have its own self regulating mechanisms, but it is not completely independent of political control.

All three theories, mercantilism, economic liberalism and Marxism have elements which are useful and relevant for today. Mercantilism recognises the need for a strong state to allow the functioning of a liberal economy by providing stability and enforcing liberal rules around the world; the hegemonic stability theory. The most relevant Marxist debate concerns development and underdevelopment in the third world. Marxists recognise underdevelopment is often caused by external economic factors and exploitation from the developed world. Economic liberals’ optimisitic and positive view of globalization shifting towards a global economic system, bringing increased prosperity yet undermining the nation state is an interesting and particularly relevant debate. None of the theories in themselves can fully explain the development of the world yet elements of each provide insights into the linkage of politics and economics.

Whilst traditional IR questions of war and peace have partially re-emerged since 9/11, the proliferation of asymmetric attacks is fundamentally different from the inter-state conflict which consumed the world in the first half of the twentieth century.  The danger of war between states, the traditional focus of IR, has declined.  Conflict in the twenty-first century is increasingly within states and often linked to issues of development and underdevelopment, an important aspect of IPE. It could be argued that to some extent the asymmetric, terrorist attacks are a result of the conflict of ideology between the liberal economies of the West and Islamist states which are threatened by the all consuming materialism and pursuit of profit sought by capitalism. Although there are other important deep underlying tensions, there is a key link between economics and politics which cannot be ignored.  The issues of wealth and poverty raised by IPE are increasingly relevant in world politics

IPE theory can do a great deal in explaining the current political and economic climate in the world and as such remains an invaluable tool in understanding IR. Its relevance extends not only to explaining the political and economic systems of the past, but can also provide indicators as to the future of the world. Attempting to study and understand international politics without consideration of the economic constraints is naïve and although complex, by examining the economic motivations of states, their political motives often become clearer.


[1] S. Strange, States and Markets, Second Edition, Pinter, 1994, p.11
[2] R. Jackson & G. Sorenson, Introduction to International Relations Theories and Approaches, Oxford University Press, 2002, p.178
[3] S. Gill & D. Law, The Global Political Economy – Perspectives, Problems and Policies, Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1998, p.7
[4] R. Jackson & G. Sorenson, Introduction to International Relations Theories and Approaches, Oxford University Press, 2002, p.178
[5] R. Gilpin, The Political Economy of International Relations, Princeton University Press, 1987, p.31
[6] ibid. p.32
[7] ibid. p32
[8] K. Knorr, British Colonial Theories, 1570-1850, University of Toronto Press, 1944, p.10
[9] R. Gilpin, The Political Economy of International Relations, Princeton University Press, 1987, p.37
[10] R. Jackson & G. Sorenson, Introduction to International Relations Theories and Approaches, Oxford University Press, 2002, p.181
[11] J. Keynes, Essays in Persuasion, Norton, 1963, p.321
[12] R. Jackson & G. Sorenson, Introduction to International Relations Theories and Approaches, Oxford University Press, 2002, p.184

0 comments:

Post a Comment